Thứ Ba, 21 tháng 8, 2018

Auto news on Youtube Aug 21 2018

Seoul's Foreign Minister expects Washington to issue more sanctions against North Korea,

unless the regime takes practical measures towards denuclearization.

She also says South Korea's efforts to establish a liaison office with the North are in line

with international sanctions.

Kim Mok-yeon reports.

Foreign Minister Kang Kyung-wha has said that the U.S. is likely to continue announcing

additional sanctions on North Korea due to Washington's strong stance that sanctions

are needed to achieve Pyongyang's denuclearization.

She made the comments at the meeting of the National Assembly's Foreign Affairs and Unification

Committee on Tuesday.

When asked whether South Korea agrees with the U.S. view that Pyongyang hasn't taken

any practical steps towards denuclearization, Kang said that she thinks it is not possible

for the two allies to completely share the same perspective, adding that despite this,

they are closely cooperating to share information on each others' situation.

Regarding concerns that Seoul could undermine international sanctions on the regime especially

through the establishment of an inter-Korean liaison office in North Korea, Kang said that

the liaison office is clearly not a violation of global sanctions, stressing that Washington

shares the same thought.

Unification minister Cho Myoung-gyon , who was also present at the meeting... went one

step further, claiming the establishment of the office could rather boost Pyongyang's

disarmament.

Concerning the upcoming inter-Korean summit expected to be held in September,... the unification

minister said that the ministry is still working to set a final date as soon as possible, and

spoke of hopes that the talks could bring peace and prosperity to the Korean peninsula.

Kim Mok-yeon, Arirang news.

For more infomation >> U.S. will continue issuing sanctions until N. Korea takes action on denuclearization.. - Duration: 1:40.

-------------------------------------------

Inter-Korean relations and denuclearization must move forward together: U.S. State Department - Duration: 0:53.

The U.S. State Department stands firm on its position that inter-Korean ties must move

forward in step with Pyongyang's denuclearization process.

A State Department official, responding to an enquiry by South Korea's Yonhap News Agency,

said the U.S. is aware that the two Koreas plan to open a joint liaison office in Kaesong.

The official did not comment on whether the project would be against the sanctions on

North Korea, but said that the restrictions remain valid until the complete denuclearization

of the regime.

The U.S. response comes after Seoul's top office rejected claims that opening an inter-Korean

liaison office at the Kaesong Industrial Complex violates international sanctions.

The State Department also said the two Koreas' road modernization project needs to go hand

in hand with Pyongyang's denuclearization process, according to VOA on Tuesday.

For more infomation >> Inter-Korean relations and denuclearization must move forward together: U.S. State Department - Duration: 0:53.

-------------------------------------------

State gubernatorial candidates square off at business forum - Duration: 1:56.

For more infomation >> State gubernatorial candidates square off at business forum - Duration: 1:56.

-------------------------------------------

Indra Gandhi full speech in US White House II 1982 visit - Duration: 10:15.

Prime Minister Gandhi Nancy and I are delighted to welcome you to the White

House and let me add a personal note it is good to see you here again as leader

of the great Indian democracy which provides a unique opportunity for us to

broaden and deepen the dialogue we began last autumn in Mexico through our Talk's

we can help to reach a renewed recognition of the mutual importance of

strong constructive ties between India and the United States in searching for

words to describe the focus of your visit to Washington this week I came

upon a statement that you had made in Delhi when Roy Jenkins visited in 1980

and at that time you said the great need in the world today is to so define

national interest that it makes for greater harmony greater equality and

justice and greater stability in the world well that is more than an eloquent

description of enlightened national interest it can also serve to describe

the foundation of the relationship between the United States and India a

relationship we seek to reaffirm this week a strengthening of that racial

relationship based on better understanding is particularly important

at this time your father once said that the basic fact of today is the

tremendous pace of change in human life the conflicts and the tensions of the

1980s posed new challenges to our countries and to all nations which seek

as India and the United States do freedom in a more stable secure and

prosperous world as leaders of the world's two largest democracies sharing

common ideals and values we can learn much from one another in discussing

concerns and exploring national purposes from this understanding can come greater

confidence in one another's roles on the world stage and a rediscovery of how

important we are to one another Prime Minister Gandhi we recognize that

there have been differences between our two countries

but these should not obscure all that we have in common for we're both strong

proud and independent nations guided by our own perceptions of our national

interests we both desire the peace and stability of the Indian Ocean area and

the early end of the occupation of Afghanistan we both seek an equitable

peace in the Middle East and an honorable settlement of the iran-iraq

conflict we both seek a constructive approach to International Economic

Cooperation building on the strong links even today being forged between the

economies of the United States and India beyond that India and the United States

are bound together by the strongest most sacred tie of all the practice of

democratic freedoms denied to many peoples by their governments my devout

hope is that during this visit we can weave together all these threads of

common interest into a new and better understanding between our two countries

welcome the United States

mr. president and mrs. Reagan to me every journey is an adventure and I can

say that this one is an adventure in search of understanding and friendship

it is difficult to imagine two nations more different than ours as history goes

your country is a young one over the years it has held unparalleled

attraction for the adventurous and daring for the talented as well as for

the persecuted it has stood for opportunity and freedom the endeavors of

the early pioneers the struggle for human values the coming together of

different races have enabled it to retain its Elan and dynamism of youth

with leadership and high ideals it has grown into a great power today its role

in world affairs is unmatched every word and action of the president is watched

and weighed and has global repercussions

India is an ancient country and history weighs heavily on us the character of

its people is formed by the palem best of its varied experiences the

circumstances of its present development are shadowed by its years of colonialism

and exploitation yet our ancient philosophy has withstood all onslaughts

absorbing newcomers adapting ideas and cultures we have developed endurance and

resilience in India our preoccupation is with building and development our

problem is not to influence others but to consolidate our political and

economic independence we believe in freedom with a passion that only those

who have been denied it can understand we believe in equality

because many in our country were so long deprived of it we believed in the worth

of the human being for that is the foundation of our democracy and our work

for development that is the framework of our national programs we have no global

interests but we are deeply interested in the world and if Affairs yet we

cannot get involved in power groupings that would be neither to our advantage

nor would it foster world peace our hand of friendship is stretched out to all

one friendship does not come in the way of another this is not a new stand that

has been my policy since I became prime minister in 1966 no two countries can

have the same angle of vision but each can try to appreciate the points of view

of the others our effort should be to find a common area

howsoever small on which to build and to enhance cooperation I take this

opportunity to say how much we in India value the help we have received from the

United States in a stupendous tasks I look forward to my talks with you mr.

president and getting to know the charming mrs. Reagan I thank you mr.

president for your kind invitation for your welcome and your gracious words I

bring to you to the first lady and to the great American people the

sincere greetings and good wishes of the government and people of India

For more infomation >> Indra Gandhi full speech in US White House II 1982 visit - Duration: 10:15.

-------------------------------------------

Airlines give US stocks a boost - Duration: 3:07.

For more infomation >> Airlines give US stocks a boost - Duration: 3:07.

-------------------------------------------

Race Heats Up For New Jersey's U.S. Senate Seat - Duration: 2:45.

For more infomation >> Race Heats Up For New Jersey's U.S. Senate Seat - Duration: 2:45.

-------------------------------------------

U.S. will continue issuing sanctions until N. Korea takes action on denuclearization.. - Duration: 1:40.

The nation's foreign and unification ministers attended a parliamentary session on diplomatic

affairs surrounding the peninsula.

Seoul's FM expects Washington to issue more sanctions against North Korea, unless the

regime takes practical measures towards denuclearization.

Kim Mok-yeon has the highlights from that session.

Foreign Minister Kang Kyung-wha has said that the U.S. is likely to continue announcing

additional sanctions on North Korea due to Washington's strong stance that sanctions

are needed to achieve Pyongyang's denuclearization.

She made the comments at the meeting of the National Assembly's Foreign Affairs and Unification

Committee on Tuesday.

When asked whether South Korea agrees with the U.S. view that Pyongyang hasn't taken

any practical steps towards denuclearization, Kang said that she thinks it is not possible

for the two allies to completely share the same perspective, adding that despite this,

they are closely cooperating to share information on each others' situation.

Regarding concerns that Seoul could undermine international sanctions on the regime especially

through the establishment of an inter-Korean liaison office in North Korea, Kang said that

the liaison office is clearly not a violation of global sanctions, stressing that Washington

shares the same thought.

Unification minister Cho Myoung-gyon , who was also present at the meeting... went one

step further, claiming the establishment of the office could rather boost Pyongyang's

disarmament.

Concerning the upcoming inter-Korean summit expected to be held in September,... the unification

minister said that the ministry is still working to set a final date as soon as possible, and

spoke of hopes that the talks could bring peace and prosperity to the Korean peninsula.

Kim Mok-yeon, Arirang news.

For more infomation >> U.S. will continue issuing sanctions until N. Korea takes action on denuclearization.. - Duration: 1:40.

-------------------------------------------

Majah Hype, 'Wickedness' says elderly J'can jailed in the US for burning a raccoon - Duration: 1:01.

it's a man in Central Florida accused of setting a raccoon on fire yeah he trying

to explain himself as he walked out of jail take a listen to this Komachi

mediafire nominee ragged lockvar la Botsford mcil one likkle report fine

about son everybody about human are lucky never see more thyroid Karma's

blood feel welcome I would understand so Meadows set a trap feed anymore

yes sir raccoon says Ezra James who after posting his $2,000 bond describes

planning to kill the animal for eating his mangos and he says to prevent it

from biting him and giving him rabies it's posted my mom in Nevada Mongolia in

the old mango seed bite him says he set the raccoon on fire after catching it

with a metal trap in his front yard right no meters while mix were chopping

our deportment satirical you know I got me I worry more dragon on it I don't

care what not next missile combat I would never believed he would have done

that

For more infomation >> Majah Hype, 'Wickedness' says elderly J'can jailed in the US for burning a raccoon - Duration: 1:01.

-------------------------------------------

Turkey files complaint against US steel and aluminum duties to WTO - Duration: 1:42.

Turkey has lodged a complaint at the World Trade Organization against additional U.S.

duties on Turkish steel and aluminium.

For more on this and other news around the world we turn to our Ro Aram…

Aram… the trade dispute between the two countries seems to be escalating….

That's right Mark…

Turkish officials had previously hinted that Ankara would initiate a dispute complaint

with the World Trade Organisation.

The WTO confirmed Monday that it has received the request.

The move comes after U.S. President Donald Trump said earlier this month that he had

authorized the doubling of tariffs on Turkish metal imports.

That would mean the tariff rate on steel would rise to 50 percent and 20 percent for aluminum.

This came amid a row over an American pastor, who is being held in Turkey on terror charges.

Last week, in retaliation, Turkey increased import duties on American goods, such as alcohol

and cars.

The diplomatic rift between the two nations has thrown Turkey's financial markets into

turmoil, with the country's currency dropping to record lows - though it has rebounded slightly.

In its complaint to the WTO, Ankara claimed Washington was violating free trade rules

when it initially imposed steel tariffs on various countries, adding that the doubling

of these rates amounts to an additional violation.

Under dispute consultations, both sides have three months to seek a solution before the

organisation's trade judges get involved.

Turkey joins Canada, Mexico and the EU, among other nations, in filing complaints at the

WTO.

For more infomation >> Turkey files complaint against US steel and aluminum duties to WTO - Duration: 1:42.

-------------------------------------------

Inter-Korean relations and denuclearization must move forward together: U.S. State Department - Duration: 0:52.

There have been concerns in some quarters that the improvements in inter-Korean ties

are getting ahead of North Korea's denuclearization.

The U.S. State Department, for one, is standing firm in its position that ties must move forward

in step with the denuclearization process.

A State Department official, responding to an enquiry by South Korea's Yonhap News Agency,

said the U.S. is aware that the two Koreas plan to open a joint liaison office in Kaesong.

South Korea has said the project would not violate international sanctions on the North.

The U.S. official wouldn't comment on that issue, but they did say the sanctions will

remain valid until the regime is denuclearized completely.

On Tuesday, VOA cited a State Department official as saying the two Koreas' project to modernize

roads in the North also needs to go in line with Pyongyang's denuclearization.

For more infomation >> Inter-Korean relations and denuclearization must move forward together: U.S. State Department - Duration: 0:52.

-------------------------------------------

US slaps more sanctions on Russia - Duration: 0:38.

The U.S. is slapping even more sanctions on Russia. The

Treasury Department is sanctioning two Russian shipping

companies it suspects are transporting petroleum products

to North Korea — which violates some U.N. Security

Council trade bans. The Associated Press reports the

Treasury is also going after two other Russian companies and two

Russians for attempting to get around U.S. sanctions set in

June. Those were imposed in response to Russian hacking and

other malicious activities conducted by the country's

military and spy organizations. That set of sanctions freezes

the companies' and Russians' assets held in the U.S.

For more infomation >> US slaps more sanctions on Russia - Duration: 0:38.

-------------------------------------------

US Space Force - What Is It And What Will It Do? (6th US Military Branch) - Duration: 8:39.

Space: the final frontier- and for our modern militaries, the indispensable 'high ground'.

Whereas decades ago, whoever controlled the sky would likely win the war, space has become

the new critical high ground that nations must protect and defend against their enemies

if they want to ensure victory.

In today's episode of The Infographics Show, we ask: Space Force: What Would It Do?

Why is space so important to a modern military?

The answer to that question lies in the unique vantage point that space provides- with a

small constellation of satellites, you can see everything happening in the world at once,

and with cloud-penetrating radar, even a rainy day won't hide the enemy from your sight.

Being able to see means being able to target an enemy with today's high-tech weapons; everything

from cruise missiles to gps guided artillery shells take advantage of advanced recon capabilities

to locate, track, and destroy an enemy.

This is why we don't carpet-bomb our foes the way we used to back in World War II.

But space is important for communications too- typical radio communications only work

for short ranges, thanks to the curvature of the earth, and can be prone to atmospheric

interference or interception/jamming by the enemy.

With a satellite in orbit though, military units can always be in direct communication

with each other, no matter where in the world they are, and satellites allow a military

to deploy advanced and very secure communication technologies that are difficult to intercept

or jam.

Basically, space is important because with eyes in the sky, you can always see your enemy,

and you can always talk to your friends.

And with so many high-tech weapon systems, there's no nation on earth that space is more

important to than the United States, who, with 123 assets in space, has nearly twice

as many military satellites as Russia, the number 2 contender, with 74.

But what would an American Space Force do exactly?

Well, at first it wouldn't be as glamorous as what you see in sci-fi movies, though given

the rate of human technological advancement, it's only a matter of time before we take

to the stars and war inevitably comes with us.

The first job of a US Space Force would be to consolidate all the various space assets

each American military service branch has.

Right now, American military satellites are divided up between the major branches of the

military: the Air Force, Army, and Navy, as well as some of the federal institutions such

as the National Reconnaissance Office.

In the event of a major war, it may be hard to coordinate between all those assets and

share information freely back and forth between the services; this is where the US Space Force

would come in.

By consolidating US space assets into a single branch of the military, the Space Force would

make it easier to coordinate the sharing of critical information and respond to enemy

attempts to sabotage or destroy American military satellites.

Commanders in a battle zone would have just one agency to ask for help from, rather than

trying to get information from multiple agencies at once.

The Space Force would also be tasked with military surveillance and reconnaissance.

It would be responsible for developing new recon technologies and coordinating with American

industry on how to best get them into space.

Once in space, the Space Force would monitor for enemy activity and be ready to immediately

raise the alarm if an attack is suspected.

But Space Force surveillance would also be important during peacetime- in recent years

American space assets have been the leading source of information on the North Korean

nuclear program.

By carefully monitoring suspected test sites, American space assets were able to determine

when underground detonations were taking place, as well as estimating yield and even giving

insights to the type of weapon tested.

Reconnaissance photos of missile test sites showed us how close to building and perfecting

a long-range missile the North Koreans actually were.

In the future, the US Space Force would take over these duties, meaning its members would

have to be on constant alert against rogue states.

Another area of responsibility for the US Space Force would be in the realm of logistics.

Where it would take a day or more to move even just a few pieces of military hardware

from one place to the next by air, sea, or land, an orbital logistics hub could have

that same hardware anywhere in the world in just a few hours.

While this is still currently outside the realm of our technology, it's not as far off

as one might think, and America's Defense Advanced Research Projects Agency, or DARPA,

has been looking into what it would take to deliver supplies from orbit to the ground

safely for years.

While in the next few years, we might see orbital drops of hardware such as food, ammunition

and medical supplies, it might not be long before American servicemen are themselves

stationed in orbit and ready to deploy within a moment's notice.

As one senior American official once said, "Getting 2,000 American boots on the ground

anywhere in the world within 2 hours could stop a lot of wars before they even begin."

But why put troops in space if you can put weapons instead?

While the militarization of space is a hot-button topic, and most American defense officials

are not eager to open up another arena of weaponized conflict, the reality is that in

all likelihood someone sooner or later will put physical weapons in space.

Despite the Outer Space Treaty banning weapons of mass destruction in space, it does not

specifically prohibit conventional weapons- a fact that the Soviet Union took advantage

of in the 1970s when it was the first, and only, nation to put a weapon in space.

Installed aboard its Almaz space station, the R-23M Kartech cannon was designed to fire

explosive shells at American space vessels.

But the Kartech was only the tip of the iceberg for what's possible if you really want to

weaponize space.

Known as 'Rods From God' and codenamed Thor, the US military studied the possibility of

creating an orbital strike platform that used nothing more than solid tungsten rods about

20 feet long and 1 foot in diameter to deliver devastating bombardments against enemy installations

or troop concentrations.

Hopelessly outnumbered by the hordes of Soviet tanks that threatened to swallow up Cold War

Europe, American scientists were looking for a way to neutralize large armored columns

without the use of nuclear weapons and thus avoid the risk of nuclear war.

They theorized that using kinetic energy alone, a telephone pole-sized rod made of solid tungsten

and equipped only with a very basic guidance package and a pair of fins, could deliver

a blast along the lines of a small tactical nuclear weapon.

Physics shows that they weren't wrong- dropped from orbit, those rods would have reached

speeds up to ten times the speed of sound.

Since Force = Mass times Acceleration, each rod would have generated an incredible amount

of energy.

Despite President Trump's executive order, the purpose and aim of the US Space Force

is still under official review, with most defense insiders saying that the need for

a dedicated space force isn't yet critical.

Yet as the expansion of the American commercial space industry has shown, humanity's expansion

into the solar system and beyond is inevitable, and as our own history shows: where man goes,

war follows.

Eventually the United States and every other modern nation on earth is going to need a

space force, or be at the mercy of those who have one.

So, what do you think about the US Space Force?

Should the US be preparing for future conflicts now so as to help prevent them in the first

place, or would it only invite other nations to start militarizing space?

Let us know your thoughts in the comments.

Also be sure to check out our other video called Moab - the Mother of All Bombs.

Thanks for watching, and, as always, don't forget to like, share, and subscribe.

See you next time!

For more infomation >> US Space Force - What Is It And What Will It Do? (6th US Military Branch) - Duration: 8:39.

-------------------------------------------

REVEALED: Meghan Markle to visit mother in US but has 'NO PLANS' to visit father Thomas Markle - Duration: 3:11.

For more infomation >> REVEALED: Meghan Markle to visit mother in US but has 'NO PLANS' to visit father Thomas Markle - Duration: 3:11.

-------------------------------------------

US deports 95-year-old former Nazi concentration camp guard - Duration: 1:01.

For more infomation >> US deports 95-year-old former Nazi concentration camp guard - Duration: 1:01.

-------------------------------------------

De Leon Calls For 3 Debates With Feinstein For U.S. Senate Seat - Duration: 1:45.

For more infomation >> De Leon Calls For 3 Debates With Feinstein For U.S. Senate Seat - Duration: 1:45.

-------------------------------------------

Trump's Tariffs Have Brought a RENAISSANCE! U.S. Steel Pledges to Invest $750 Million - Duration: 2:57.

For more infomation >> Trump's Tariffs Have Brought a RENAISSANCE! U.S. Steel Pledges to Invest $750 Million - Duration: 2:57.

-------------------------------------------

US-China trade war already hurting US auto industry: John Bozzella - Duration: 2:51.

For more infomation >> US-China trade war already hurting US auto industry: John Bozzella - Duration: 2:51.

-------------------------------------------

Comparing Internet Access In Rural SD To Other States - Duration: 2:06.

For more infomation >> Comparing Internet Access In Rural SD To Other States - Duration: 2:06.

-------------------------------------------

A Perfect Storm: U.S. Health Care Spending with M. Kate Bundorf - Duration: 1:04:19.

Today I thought I would, as I'm sure everyone knows healthcare reform

is a very important and controversial topic right now.

And today,

what I wanted to do in this talk was kind of take step back a little bit.

To talk about what are the fundamental drivers of our healthcare system.

And if we have some time at the end, we can talk about putting, and

I'll try to do this as I go through the talk,

putting some of those drivers into the context of healthcare reform.

Hopefully this will give us all a better sense of how to put

some of the arguments floating around out there into context and kind of figure out

the real from the rhetoric in the context of healthcare reform.

So I thought I would talk about it in the context of the perfect storm.

Why is healthcare spending so high in the US?

And my overall take on this is that there's really no one reason why

healthcare spending is so high in the US.

We have a very complicated system and there are different points in the system

which contribute to our high overall levels of spending.

So in this talk we're going to think a little bit about how do we evaluate high

spending and what are the factors that lead to high spending.

Okay so let's just start at the very beginning.

These are data from OECD showing healthcare spending in the US and

other countries.

Probably many people are at least generally familiar with these statistics.

But this is per-capita spending, in the United States we're number one.

Right, so our healthcare spending is over now,

this was 2011, over $8,000 per person in the US per year.

If you compare this to other countries, obviously this is much higher, right?

So these are all the other OECD countries along the x-axis.

And healthcare spending, the next closest country is,

two countries are Norway and Switzerland at around $5,500.

These are what's called purchasing power parity adjusted.

So these are generally adjusted for

differences in kind of the spending power of people in different countries.

Norway and Switzerland are the next two countries, at just over $5,000 per person.

To make this even more striking, I've divided the spending bars into spending

financed by public programs, those are the dark blue bars at the bottom.

And spending financed privately by individuals and

private insurers, those are the lighter bars at the top.

Right, so in the US we have a much greater reliance on private spending.

Right, so our private spending bar is a bigger share of overall spending than

other countries do.

But the striking thing to me is when you look at spending in the US,

the amount per person that we spend through public programs

exceeds the entire spending of many other countries.

High income developed countries, Sweden, Australia, Ireland and the United Kingdom,

those are the ones I've highlighted here.

So just the amount we spend on our public programs,

which cover less than half of the population,

exceeds the entire spending of many other high-income countries.

Right, so to me in some ways, that's the most surprising thing.

Right, that kind of puts it into context.

Okay, so we clearly spend more on healthcare in the US than other counties,

and we're gonna talk about why that is.

But I want to make a couple important points first about

thinking about this higher spending.

And these points are related to the fact that, for some reasons,

healthcare spending should be higher in the US than in other countries.

One reason is that we are a high-income country.

And as people become wealthier,

they tend to spend a greater proportion of their budget on healthcare.

So as you become wealthier,

healthcare is something that becomes more important to you, to many people.

And they tend to spend a higher proportion of their budget.

This is holding other factors constant such as your health status, etc.

But an economist would call a normal good or you can think of it as a luxury good,

it's something that we want more of as we become higher income.

So because the US is a higher income country,

we would naturally spend more on healthcare than other countries.

The other point that's important, and I think is a little bit more subtle,

is that in the US, often we spend more on healthcare

because healthcare is a very labor intensive industry.

And in the US, we have very productive workers.

So our workers are productive, so

we need to pay them more to reflect their productivity.

In other industries, such as manufacturing,

we can kinda substitute between labor and capital, right?

So as workers become more productive and we pay them more,

we move more towards capital, machines and things in the context of production.

But we can't do that in healthcare so readily,

healthcare is a very labor intensive industry.

We have nurses, and physicians,

and home health aides who help us in the context of healthcare.

That means the healthcare industry is competing against other industries for

workers.

As a result of that, we have to pay those workers more.

Right, to make sure that we have high quality workers in the healthcare

industry, we need to pay those workers more.

So one of the reasons, and an important reason, why healthcare is more expensive

in the US than other countries is the productivity of our labor force and

the fact that healthcare is a very labor intensive industry.

This is a similar argument for why is a haircut more in the US than in China.

Right, so we pay our workers more in the US for

reasons related to their productivity.

Okay, so there are valid reasons why we would spend more on healthcare in the US.

People haven't done really comprehensive decompositions on the impact of these

factors, but we have a sense that this doesn't explain it all.

Even accounting for these things, which are important, we certainly spend more.

But this does raise a question, an important question, of how much is enough.

How much should we be spending on healthcare?

Is the amount that we're spending right, or is it too much, or is it too little?

Economists have a very

specific way of thinking about how much spending is enough.

And that is if the benefits of what we're getting from that spending

on healthcare exceeds the cost, then it's okay.

What we worry about is that we're devoting money to healthcare

on services for which the costs are greater than the benefits.

Those resources might be better off in some other sector of our economy.

We could devote them to education, we could devote them to more iPads,

we could spend it in other ways.

So that's the biggest concern, When we're thinking about overall spending.

We have evidence from lots of different types of studies that this is a problem

in the US.

Right, so researchers estimate that maybe between 20 and

30% of the amount that we spend on healthcare provides no health benefits.

Right, so that's a really important statement.

That's saying we're spending money and it's not obvious that we're getting a lot,

or getting anything in the form of improved health from that spending.

So when we think about is our healthcare spending too high,

to me this is the big argument.

Right, so we're spending money on the healthcare system in ways that are not

improving our health.

Okay so, to kind of put this into context or put this into real life, let's consider

the case of colorectal cancer screening, we'll come back to this as we go along.

So colorectal cancer screening,

there are a variety of different ways that we can screen for colorectal cancer.

And it turns out that those different ways of screening

have very different price tags associated with them.

So there are a variety of ways.

I'm gonna focus on two here, colonoscopy and fecal immunochemical testing,

most people refer to this as FIT as two examples.

These two tests, this is a much more invasive test.

You only have to do this once every 10 years.

It's recommended once every 10 years.

The price tag for this is $1,200.

Right, so every time you get a colonoscopy, it costs about $1,200.

That's how much the insurer would pay the physician performing the colonoscopy.

We have an alternative which is a fecal test.

It's recommended that if you're gonna go to this route that you should do it

annually.

We estimate by looking at insurance claims that the cost of that is

about $20 per year, right.

So, the colonoscopy you get it done in one shot, and it costs $1,200.

The FIT test you have to do it every year, $20 per year, so

that's gonna be about $200 over your 10 year period.

Most evidence we have on the effectiveness of these two tests

is that their effectiveness is about equal, right?

So at the end of the day, your health outcomes associated with these two

screening tests are gonna be about the same.

In the US, the vast majority of screening is colonoscopy.

So in the US, our system is set up to do colonoscopies.

Interestingly, other countries mostly use alternative tests.

Some use FIT, other uses different lower cost screening tests.

But our system kind of systematically steers people towards the most

expensive test.

One thing I like about this example, though,

is the price difference is very large.

So you think, oh, should we really be doing colonoscopies at $1,200,

versus FIT at 200 bucks.

But often when I'm doing this in class,

we're in Silicon Valley so we use our cell phones.

And we vote, right, with our cell phones, and

the results pop up right up here on the screen.

So when I do this with my students in the class, and

I say okay, you're gonna spend $1,200 on the colonoscopy.

Pretend you're 50 or older, or you can go $20 per year over ten years for the FIT,

many of the students do the FIT, but a subset always chooses the colonoscopy.

And you can think they're probably are valid reasons.

You only have to go in once every ten years.

It's a little more uncomfortable, but you only have to go in once every ten years.

So there are probably valid reasons some people might be willing to pay 1,200 for

a colonoscopy.

But many people, when faced with this price difference, would choose the FIT.

Okay, so why do we do so

many colonoscopies in the US rather than the FIT?

My thesis here is that there's not really one easy answer.

But there are kind of three major points or

junctures or pressure points in the US health care system, and

each of those points kind of encourage us to do more expensive things.

So what I'm gonna do now is kind of build up what I mean by the health care system,

talk about what each of those three points are, and

we'll put colonoscopies into that system.

So you can start by thinking about how do patients access care?

So we have patients.

They want healthcare services, or they need healthcare services.

And they go to providers, all right.

So here I'm thinking about providers very generally, physicians don't

usually like being called providers, they like being called physicians, but

I'm thinking about this a little bit more broadly.

I'm thinking about all different types of workers in the healthcare system who

provide different types of care.

Patients get services from providers, and

if we didn't have a healthcare system, they would pay them directly, right.

This isn't usually how it works, right?

When you go in to seek medical care,

you don't just pay that $1,200 for the colonoscopy.

It usually goes to your insurance.

Why do we have insurance?

Why do we have this more complicated system?

The reason we have insurance or the reason that our system is more

complicated is that there's an incredible financial risk associated with healthcare.

So it's not so obvious in the case of the simple colorectal cancer screening test,

but when you think about something like delivery, for example.

A woman could have a normal uncomplicated delivery,

and that would cost about $5,000.

She could have complications,

the infant could be admitted to the neonatal intensive care unit, and

that would cost hundreds of thousands of dollars, all right.

So by having insurance, we protect ourselves against the financial risk

associated with sickness or

health care events, that is important to folks.

So now we need to introduce an insurance setup.

So now instead of having patients, we have people.

We have the entire population, and instead of paying directly to providers,

now we're sending money into what I'll call payers.

Payers are health insurers.

These organizations that are set up very differently in different countries.

So in the US we have a lot of private insurers.

In other countries the government plays a much more active role in being

the health care insurer.

But people generally pay either taxes or

they pay health insurance premiums into payers.

Payers then turn around and make payments to the people who provide care.

So now instead of having the bulk of the payment go from the patient to

the provider, now we have a new channel.

People have paid money into these health insurers or payers.

The payers in turn make a payment to the provider when an individual seeks care.

And patients, as most of you are probably familiar with, often pay a little bit, or

some, or maybe sometimes what sometimes feels like a lot.

In addition to the payment that that health care provider is

receiving from an insurer.

So this is the basic outline of a health care system.

Obviously, it's much more complex, but

you can think about this as a stylized health care system.

Okay, so now that we have this system up and running,

we can really think about three pressure points in the system, three places in

which we can create incentives to provide high value as opposed to high cost care.

When I say high value care,

I'm thinking about care for which the benefits exceeds the cost.

So for people who would actually rather spend $200 over ten years for

FIT rather than colonoscopy, how can we create incentives for

that to happen in our system?

So one of these pressure points is the amount of money that people pay for

health insurance, right, and

this is actually becoming more important in the context of health care reform.

Right, and what I mean by this is if I were out shopping for a health insurance

premium, I would be comparing the premiums across different private health insurers.

A health insurer that really funnels people into using tests like FIT

as opposed to a colonoscopy is going to have much lower health insurance premiums.

Maybe colorectal cancer screening by itself

might not make that much of a difference.

But a health insurer that systematically is pushing or encouraging people

to use higher value care would likely have lower health insurance premiums.

So one way we can kind of create incentives for

using care more parsimoniously or focusing care on high value

care is by having people face health insurance premiums.

Lower premium plans will often be plans that, plans will then have an incentive To

structure their systems in a way that provide different types of care.

So health insurance premiums is one juncture, or one pressure point.

Another pressure point is the way we pay health care providers, right?

So you can think in the context of colonoscopy.

A physician who routinely sends people off to get a FIT test,

actually doesn't make that much money off that FIT test, right?

The test is pretty cheap, the physician doesn't have that much to do.

But physicians who provide colonoscopies,

colonoscopies are actually much more profitable by physicians,

when they are paid every time they do a colonoscopy, right.

So when you think about that,

now the physician, say the two tests are equally effective, now the physician

has a financial incentive to do a colonoscopy rather than a FIT.

You could change those payment incentives.

You could change the way providers are paid, and

turn those incentives upside down.

So for example, if the physicians were part of a large group, and

that group was paid what's called a capitated fee, a set amount for

providing care to a population over a particular time period,

now the physician's incentives are reversed, right?

So now the physician thinks,oh, if I steer the person away

from the really expensive test, [COUGH] excuse me.

If I steer that person away from the really expensive test,

then my organization will make more money because I won't have to pay for

that very, I actually lost my water here, going way over here to get my water.

I know I'm gonna cough more.

[COUGH] So now that I've capitated the group,

now the physician has very different incentives, right?

So now that the physicians have incentives to provide these lower cost tests.

In the case of a colorectal cancer screening,

I've said those tests are approximately equally effective.

So the physician is making this decision across a margin of equal effectiveness.

Let's go for the lower cost test.

So provider payments are another kind of pressure point in the system.

We have lots of evidence from research that says the way you pay physicians

really matters.

Okay, so our final kind of pressure point,

is the relationship between patients and providers.

The issue here is basically how much people pay out of pocket

when they seek care.

So when I told you about those different screening modalities,

one test was about $1,200, and the other test was about $200.

In the context of insurance for preventive services, usually those tests,

and specifically in this case,

always those tests are free at the point of service, right?

So if I think oh, the colonoscopy might be a little bit better, I have

no financial incentive to think about the cost difference between those two tests.

So when health policy folks talk about the role of cost sharing,

they're thinking about the incentives or

kind of the good role of cost sharing in context of the health care system.

They're thinking about those types of incentives, right.

When people have to pay some out of pocket for

the more expensive tests, then they have a greater incentive to really

think about the benefits of those tests relative to the costs.

Okay, so those are the three kind of pressure points in our healthcare system.

We can think about premiums and people shopping for different types of plans and

choosing lower premium plans.

We can thing about how providers are paid, and

we can also think about how patients pay for care when they seek services.

Okay, so now let's put this stylized system in the context of the U.S.

healthcare system.

Starting at that first pressure point,

are people sensitive to premiums when they choose among different plans?

When we look at overall rates of health insurance coverage in the U.S.,

about 30% of our population is covered by public programs.

Those are Medicare for older and

disabled folks, Medicaid, generally for low-income folks.

The other big payer is our employers, right?

So the bulk of the working population gets their health insurance through employers.

So now let's think about those premium incentives.

Where is the premium signal in those two ways of obtaining health insurance?

Starting with employer-sponsored health insurance,

employer-sponsored health insurance is really tricky, right?

So when you think about how people choose among different employer-sponsored plans,

when they have a choice, usually they're thinking about their out of

pocket payment that the employer requires of them when they enroll in the plan.

Usually that's a very small part of the premium, right.

So when people are choosing among different plans, they're not really,

usually thinking about the full cost consequences of their choice.

But there's actually a bigger issue here.

The bigger issue is that when people buy health insurance through their employer,

it turns out that that premium is subsidized through the tax system.

And the reason that it's subsidized through the tax system, is when I get my

health insurance through Stanford, I don't report that as my wage income.

And that's perfectly legal, right, so

you guys don't have to go tell anyone about that.

>> [LAUGH] >> [LAUGH] Everyone does it.

So by law it's counted as wage compensation for me or

anyone who gets health insurance through an employer, right?

So when I am thinking about oh, so

I have a family, so the health insurance premium for me is about $15,000.

That's an important distinction, right?

So I could get that $15,000 as cash compensation and pay taxes on it,

or I could get that $15,000 in the form of health insurance and not pay taxes on it.

For people with high marginal tax rates,

say 30, 40, 50%, that is a big price discount, right?

So think if cars were subsidised that way, maybe I wouldn't drive a Prius.

Maybe I'd have a Tesla, right?

If I could get that big discount on the Tesla, but

that's what health insurance looks like in the US.

So, and it's actually a very Interesting policy.

It creates an subsidy for health insurance, and

I think most people in the health policy world think that is good.

We actually want to encourage people to have some health insurance.

But the design of that subsidy is saying, we are going to give bigger subsidies to

higher income people and low or almost no subsidies to lower income people.

And that's because that tax exclusion is more valuable for high income folks.

Okay, so this is important from that perfect storm argument cuz that says those

people with employer-sponsored health insurance, they're getting kind of 30,

40, 50% off the price of health insurance.

That means they want generous health insurance.

They want the Tesla,

they don't want the Prius when they're buying health insurance.

What does generous health insurance mean?

That means health insurance that covers colonoscopies, right?

So a less generous plan would mean health insurance that really funnels people into

getting FIT.

If you want a colonoscopy,

you can get a colonoscopy in a more generous health plan.

Okay, so that's the employer-sponsored health insurance has these incentives for

kind of more care or less value conscious care.

Medicare has similar issues, Medicare and Medicaid,

but more Medicare, but the mechanism is a little bit different.

Usually when people think about Medicare

you don't think about your premium for coverage.

That's because Medicare is tax financed.

So we effectively lose that premium signal

in the context of Medicare because we're financing it through taxes.

The people who are financing Medicare, people who are using

the services now, when they were younger, they were paying into the Medicare system.

Young folks now, who are paying for

Medicare of the currently older population.

They're a large and diffuse group.

Right? So,

and my students, it's really hard to get them excited about Medicare reform even

though they're the ones paying for it.

Right? I keep trying that but

they're not really receptive.

But the point here is there really isn't a premium signal, right?

So we think that we need a premium premium signal to promote high value care.

But the people who are paying for Medicare at a given point in time, the tax payers,

are generally different than the people who are using the Medicare systems.

We've kind of lost that signal in the context of Medicare.

Okay, so let's think about the second pressure point in the system,

that's how providers are paid.

The example that I gave you, the providers and

physician incentives for doing colonoscopies versus recommending fit

were very different depending how they were paid.

When they got paid by fee-for-service, for example,

they had a very strong incentive to do the colonoscopy, but when they were paid that

capitated fee, they had a very strong incentive to move folks to fit.

It turns out in our healthcare system, we usually pay providers in ways

that promote higher cost care,

or promote providers, promote physicians to do more stuff, essentially.

We usually pay them by fee-for-service.

We give them a fee for every single thing we do.

In the context of hospitals we usually pay per admission.

So as long as the fee covers the cost associated with the admission,

physicians generally have incentive to admit people more often.

Admit people if you think there's any possibility that they need to be admitted.

Probably more controversial is you have very little incentive

as a hospital to make sure a person doesn't get readmitted, for example.

Right? So if something goes wrong,

the hospital actually makes more money if the person is readmitted down the road.

So many of our payment systems are geared towards doing more stuff.

I think this is related to our last point, right?

So we talked about how people have incentives to

buy more generous health insurance, or we have little incentives to make sure

health insurers are delivering care parsimoniously.

That translates into kind of little will to change payment systems.

Right? So now we all want the Tesla, so

we all want to make sure that we'll get admitted if there's any shadow of a doubt.

Okay, the third mechanism here is what economists,

or benefits folks, would call benefit design, right.

So how is the health insurance contract designed?

And I think this is a little bit nonintuitive,

what I'm about to say to folks, because I think there's a perception out there that

cost sharing has really increased a lot, right.

That people spend a lot out of pocket when they go in to seek healthcare.

But if you actually look at the long-term trend in out-of-pocket spending

as a proportion of total spending, it has consistently declined over time.

Right?

So in 1970, as a population we paid

about 35% of total health care spending out of pocket.

In 2011 we paid about 11% of total health care spending out of pocket, and

what's the source of disconnect between the perception and then the actual data?

The issue is that healthcare spending has increased so dramatically.

Right. So that 11% really feels like

a lot because the base is so high.

We spend a lot more on healthcare.

But the general issue is that cost sharing,

at least as a portion of total overall spending, has declined overtime.

In cost sharing we have lots of studies that show this is important for

how people make decisions at the point of care.

So this is equivalent to saying that,

if I charge people 10% of the price of the colonoscopy and

10% of the price of the fit, probably a lot more people would go with the fit as

opposed to the colonoscopy in the context of colorectal cancer screening.

Okay, so costs, so

in our health care system, folks who are health policy folks who say,

oh cost sharing needs to be higher, they're not necessarily mean, right?

They're basically saying we need more cost sharing in order to steer people to making

more value conscious choices in the health care system.

Okay, so that's the overall system, but one thing I want, or how the different

incentives that each of those pressure points, in my view,

are really kind of pushing us towards using more and using more expensive care.

I want to reinforce this idea that all those things work together.

The fact that we don't have these premium signals leads payers to pay

their providers in certain ways, in ways that don't promote high value care.

If people were more conscious of the premium, maybe they would purchase a plan

that creates strong incentives for providers to use different types of care.

But because many of us are getting that 50% discount and folks are on Medicare and

not paying for it directly,

there's not this ground swell of demand for more value conscious care.

Okay. How am I doing on time?

Okay. Okay.

So let's talk a little bit about healthcare reform and

how healthcare reform is going to hit our

three points.

Health care reform, in many ways, is really targeted or

the main purpose of healthcare reform, where healthcare reform is the strongest,

this is the Affordable Care Act that I'm sure you all have heard about,

especially in the last few weeks, as it's being implemented in many ways.

A lot of the Affordable Care Act was about expanding insurance coverage, right?

So that's really going to affect this area, right?

So as I showed you on the earlier slide,

we have about 15% of the population that's uninsured.

Many of the issues in the Affordable Care Act, many of the mechanisms

in the Affordable Care Act are intended to increase insurance coverage for that 15%.

One of the things that President Obama talked about when he passed the Act is if

you have health insurance now, it's not gonna change very much.

Right? So I just got through telling you that

many of the ways we provide health insurance

now are not promoting value conscious care.

So really the changes to the health insurance market aren't really intended

to promote more value conscious care, they're really intended to kind of bring

folks in to this existing health care system that we have.

The folks who get health insurance coverage, those going to the exchanges,

are actually going to see some premium differentials and

have some incentive to choose these lower cost plans,

but they're a relatively small proportion of the market.

Right, so

there's not a lot of action on the health insurance premium side in the law.

If we think about provider payments, most of the reforms that were

proposed as part of the Affordable Care Act were focused on the Medicare program.

And the reason for this is that, because the government runs Medicare,

the government has much more control over the Medicare,

how providers are paid in the context of Medicare.

That's important because a lot of provider revenue

comes from treating Medicare patients.

So there's a lot of experimentation in the context of Medicare right now.

And that kind of remains to be seen.

Some folks are skeptical that that will actually spread through the entire

healthcare system.

Other folks are concerned that it might not even make a big dent in the Medicare

program.

But I think the thing the Affordable Care Act did that was good in that context,

was really promote this type of experimentation, and

we'll have to watch that as we go along.

So I would say that incentives are not strong, but

it did put a mechanism in to kind of think about different ways of organizing care to

promote higher value care.

And in terms of cost sharing I think there wasn't a lot of action, there wasn't a lot

of push on promoting higher value care through higher cost sharing.

There might be that segment of the population which is newly insured, and

it is insured in a slightly different way through health insurance exchanges, that

might kind of be induced to enroll in plans that have higher

cost sharing because they're seeing the premium savings up front when they enroll.

But that is a relatively small segment of the population.

Okay, so let's go to conclusions.

Then we will have some time for some questions.

So I think that overall, if you look at the healthcare system there

really are incentives to promote high value care at those three critical points.

The point at which people are paying for health insurance premiums,

the point at which health insurers are paying providers, and

the point at which people are seeking care.

In our current healthcare system, we really have, the incentives are towards

doing more and doing more expensive things at each of those points.

So in order to get around this,

in order to really fundamentally change the incentives of the healthcare system,

we really need to think about reform at multiple points in that system.

So the pieces of the system work together.

The most important example being that when people had incentives on the premium front

for choosing lower cost plans, that gave health insurance providers incentives to

really change the way they pay health insurers for example, right.

So when we talk about how complex the healthcare system is and

whether the Affordable Care Act will fundamentally change it,

I think part of the complication here is that all these points in

the healthcare system work together.

And if you really want to reform it in a comprehensive way,

you have to think about those interactions.

Okay, thank you.

>> [APPLAUSE] >> Okay, let's see.

>> A couple questions.

>> Okay, I'll give you one and then I gotta go to these other guys, okay?

Is that okay?

>> Okay. >> Okay.

[LAUGH] >> Well, a while I go, I was curious about

what Kaiser would charge me if I didn't have Medicare.

>> Mm-hm. >> It was over 1,000 bucks.

>> That's good.

>> Now- >> [LAUGH]

>> Now I pay Kaiser 72 bucks a month.

Is Medicare paying over 900 for me?

>> Yes, Medicare is paying, so you're covered by Medicare.

Yes, if you're enrolled in a, let's go back here.

So if you are, there we go.

So the things that I was describing are more the,

what we call traditional Medicare.

Medicare pays your health providers.

If you're enrolled in what's called a Medicare managed care plan,

it works a little bit differently.

What happens in q Medicare managed care plan is that there's another step here.

This is the US government, this is the Medicare program.

The Medicare program pays a private insurer,

draw a little circle up here representing Kaiser.

Pays a private insurer a lot,

maybe 90% for your health insurance.

And then you pay maybe about 10% for that health care, right?

So, even when you're enrolled in a managed care plan in the context of Medicare,

the government is giving you a very large subsidy for that care.

As they should, because they promised you the care, right?

>> How much salary do the docs get?

>> Okay, I gave you one question, I gotta go.

Right, I'm in a medical school, it's a little sensitive, right.

[LAUGH] So I'm gonna go green up there in the back.

You didn't talk anything about the quality.

>> Yeah. >> What's the quality of

our outcomes versus other citizens?

>> Mm-hm.

>> And Isn't the issue not just bringing down our cost but improving our quality?

>> Absolutely, so quality is important and quality is very controversial.

And I think the reason for that is, in some contexts,

that the US is the best in the world, is true.

In other contexts, it's not, right.

So quality can be very variable across different settings and

even across different types of diseases, right?

So for example, what's a good quality example?

And it plays out in ways that you might not expect.

The example that I gave you, quality was kind of constant

across those two incentives, or those two different treatments.

If you think about, it turns out that we have, I think this one's good.

It turns out that probably one of the most frequently

cited quality metrics is infant mortality rates.

Right, so we spend a lot more on care and delivering babies,

and we don't actually have great outcomes in the context of infant mortality rates.

But it turns out if you look at the data more closely, if you are a premature

infant we have very good outcomes, conditional on being born premature.

We have fantastic neonatal intensive care units and

they have better outcomes than other countries.

Where things differ in the US is we have more babies who are born at

very low birth weight.

And then we have, I just saw some very interesting kind of new research,

presented at a conference, where they showed that the infant mortality

rates between six months and one year are actually worse in the US.

Right so I think that's one of those really interesting,

it's really hard to make a generalization based on infant mortality rates

because in some contexts our system is really good, right?

If you're born as a low birth weight infant,

you want to be in Stanford Hospital or an academic medical center.

But there are kind of funny things going on before the baby's born and

after the baby's born that maybe are not so good.

Red hat, that's everyone, oh my gosh.

>> [LAUGH] >> Red hat and blue jacket.

[LAUGH] >> So, are there any incentives

with the Obamacare Act that will push more people

out of employee based health care payments, and

into, paying insurers directly, and

is that something that would help the overall system?

>> Yeah so that's a really interesting question.

And I think that when- >> Could you repeat the question.

>> Sure.

So, the question has two parts, and it's about the incentives and

the Affordable Care Act in the context of employer sponsored systems.

The first part of the question is,

will the Affordable Care Act really push people out of employment based coverage,

and then the second part is is that a good thing or a bad thing?

So the first question, the answer to the first question is we don't know.

Right? And why don't we know?

Because it's actually a really hard problem

to know what is going on inside a firm and what employers are going to do.

And here's the issue.

The fundamental issue is that for high income workers,

high income workers still get that really big tax subsidy that I talked about

only by getting their health insurance through an employer.

So high income workers really want health insurance through employers.

Now low income workers, things have really changed for

them, especially in states that expanded Medicaid.

Right?

So now those low income workers get a much bigger subsidy

if their employer doesn't offer health insurance.

Right? They get a big subsidy if they go buy

their insurance through an exchange, if they're like a higher, low income worker,

and if they're a really low income worker then they are eligible for

a Medicaid expansion.

So now the employer is like, oh no, what do I do?

Right? So I have some low income workers,

and the best thing for them is for me to not offer them health insurance.

I have some high income workers, and the best thing for

me to do is to continue offering health insurance for them.

So that's why we don't know, because it kind of depends on how employers are gonna

respond to those trade offs.

And we've seen some really high profile examples in the news,

I think it was Trader Joe's and organizations like that,

who started at that part time worker distinction.

Not offering coverage for their part-time workers because, in fact,

it was better for them, most of them, to get coverage through an exchange.

So what are the cost implications of that?

I think the important point here is the cost implications of

moving people into exchange or subsidized coverage and out

of employment based coverage, that, turns out, is also a very interesting issue.

So let's pretend, maybe, it's possible, that people will be more price

sensitive when they get into the exchange and make more value conscious decisions.

We're not sure that that's gonna happen but let's just say that happens.

That's good for overall health care spending in the U.S.

and as long as those are high quality plans then we feel good about that.

On the flip side, that is going to dramatically increase government spending.

Right, cuz now all those people are gonna get a subsidy, and for

the low income folks, the subsidy is going to be larger than

what they would have had under an employer, so there's a really big tension.

I think this is an important distinction that people don't often make

when they're talking about the Affordable Care Act, is there are often very

different implications for government spending, which is very important, and

total healthcare spending, which is also very important.

Okay I'm going way over to the guy in the red sweatshirt.

With the [LAUGH] glasses.

Raising his hand really high.

Okay. >> My question is you did a good

job explaining the card system.

If you were to start with a blank slate,

taking into account realities of the world, and

US, what kind of system would you design?

[INAUDIBLE] at least an equally effective, if not a more effective,

health care outcome, and obviously cost us a lot less money.

What would you do?

>> Yeah, so this is a point where I really wish I'd written a book.

Right, so I could say, and, give my answer and then say, and, go buy my book.

Right? But I can't, so

I'm not gonna get any royalties from my statement, which is unfortunate.

I think the answer is- >> Could you repeat the questions?

>> I'm sorry the question.

So the question is like the eternal question.

What is the perfect, if I could start from scratch and

design a healthcare system, what would I do.

I think that it is difficult

to reform the US healthcare system because there are lots of vested interests.

That sounds a little negative but people who are accustomed to doing

things in a certain way and kinda like doing them that way.

So I think if I had to do it, I would have,

there are some things I like about the Affordable Care Act.

I think I would try to start here.

I would try to start by saying, okay, and

this is the, I am an economist and they call us the dismal science.

This is an example of why that is true.

So this is one of the most least popular policy prescriptions that

almost all economists agree would be a good thing.

I would get rid of that employer sponsored tax exclusion.

It seems like such a micro little problem.

Like in the tax code, all of our problems are driven by the tax code?

But I think it's important.

I think it's important that when people are choosing health insurance,

they have some sense.

I think even I am astounded, I spend my life studying this and I am astounded that

when I look at how much Stanford pays for health insurance for me, they're

paying about $15,000 for my healthy family and I to be covered by health insurance.

That seems like a lot.

I think that if people actually didn't have a big subsidy and

saw their health insurance premiums, plans, health insurance,

private health insurance plans in the U.S.

would have much stronger incentives to innovate in really interesting ways.

I also think that this is a pretty good time for

innovation in really interesting ways because my quality guy up here is right.

For plans to innovate in interesting ways, to keep them honest,

we really need good measures of quality.

If I'm gonna sign up for a cheaper plan, I want to know that that's a decent quality

plan, that I really am getting the Prius and I'm not getting the, what's the loop.

I'm from Detroit so I would have said the Chevy a few years ago but

I don't think I can really say that anymore, I think they've improved.

But I don't want to enroll in low quality.

I want to enroll in a low price plan that provides high quality care and

we need quality metrics in order to do that.

But I think data revolution, things are moving along on that front.

Okay, white jacket. >> I noticed that you haven't recommended

that the government take over the care system as exists in Europe.

Do you not like that system?

Do you feel doesn't work as well?

>> Yes.

I have not recommended that.

I have, for two reasons.

When I talked about how payers interact with providers, that's really important.

In that context, it's actually not obvious that public or

private payers, public governance, when I say private payers,

private insurers, have an advantage over you.

Either side has an advantage.

The types of things I'm talking about, what I mean by that,

is the types of things that I'm talking about, changing the way you pay providers

can be done either by private health insurance or by public programs, right.

So this is a matter of experimentation to figure out what works and making sure that

these payers have incentives to really drive efficient utilization of care.

So this is an area where I think we don't know exactly what the perfect

system looks like, but all the things that we have on the table,

are equally available to public or private insurers.

The thing that worries me about the one government system,

is the colonoscopy, right?

And so what I mean by that, is that if we had one government system,

we could say everyone should have Fit, right?

And we'll just do it that way.

And we'll encourage people through our coverage decision, into this test.

But remember when I said I kind of liked this example, because there are lots of

people out there who would be perfectly happy to pay $1200 for the colonoscopy.

And that's not obviously, not just this test, that's along many different margins.

All right, so I feel like we are a very heterogeneous country, and

the single payer, one size fits all might not be so good for us, right.

So I worry about that.

>> [INAUDIBLE] >> Oh, I got everyone going.

>> Can you explain the lower cost that exists within the governmental

care [INAUDIBLE] >> Yeah, often it's lower costs, but

sometimes, you know you get what you pay for, right?

So. >> [INAUDIBLE] funded healthcare.

[INAUDIBLE] funded public

healthcare, is terrible.

>> [INAUDIBLE] wouldn't provide assistance for the entire country.

>> [INAUDIBLE] >> Okay,

I'm gonna have to have you guys take this outside.

Take this outside, okay?

[LAUGH] We have lots more questions.

I'm gonna go for the guy standing in the back since he's been standing.

>> Thanks.

[INAUDIBLE] >> ACOs will succeed, if you think they

will, especially in the context of the HMO history in the past?

>> So the question is, why will ACO's exceed and

draw some parallels to the managed care in the past?

So, what is an ACO?

So, an ACO is an accountable care

organization, >> Oops.

An ACO is over here basically, and what an ACO is doing,

is an ACO as I said, reform is really focused on Medicare.

What Medicare is doing is basically encouraging Hospitals and

physicians to get together, and form kind of larger either contractually based or

actual really integrated organizations.

And then change the way they're paid.

And it's a little bit complicated.

The way that they're changing the payment, is they are saying that, organization,

we will tell you who is generally receiving care through your organization.

The patients who tend to usually seek care from physicians,

that you are grouped with now.

And then we're going to pay you a new way.

We are gonna predict how much it would cost under traditional medicare for

all the care for these patients.

And we'll give you a bonus, if you come in under that, right?

So it's called shared savings.

You provide care in more value conscious way, and you can earn some money and

Medicare will save some money.

I think that that's kind of a step in the right direction.

The problem in the context of Medicare is to make it politically valuable,

they really had to water it down a lot.

So there's not the magnitude of the shared savings, is not so great.

Many of you are probably enrolled in accountable care organizations and

have no idea.

The reason for that is, the accountable care organization can't

actually make you stay within it's network, Right.

To make a this a politically palatable reform,

because of our experience with managed care where it turned out that people

didn't really like to be restricted to a particular set of providers,

now in the context of ACO's, ACO's can't make that restriction.

So you have to be able to go anywhere you want.

So that kind of limits the ability of ACO's to really manage your care and

the relatively weakened financial incentives create weak incentives for

them to really even try.

So I feel a little bit skeptical on the ACO's.

Let's see, I'm gonna go with the gray, blonde hair.

Yep.

>> What about alternative modalities and vetted care?

Do you have any addition to how that might be worked in to

the system because it's not being used, it's not part of our current perspective.

>> Yeah so I. So I'm all for

preventive care, right, and preventative care and alternative modalities,

I think, you mean like alternative medicine, basically,

how do they fit into the healthcare system and what are the opportunities.

I think preventive care is obviously very important.

The evidence on the impact of preventative care on health care spending,

is that we actually aren't going to reduce our health care spending much,

if at all, by promoting more preventive care.

And, there are two things going on there.

Preventive care is good, because when it works, people won't get sick and

we like that.

One issue is that, if I look at all of you guys,

I'm not sure who's gonna get sick, right?

So I have to give preventative care to a lot of people

in order to prevent one person from getting sick.

And that makes it expensive.

It might be worth it, right, because we highly value the fact that that

one person, or those three people, or even those fifteen people, aren't going to get

that particular disease, but it does make it more expensive.

The way to make it more cost effective clearly, is to

figure out who might get sick and focus your preventative care spending that way.

And that's a good thing to the extent that we can do it.

But there are very few preventative interventions that literally save money.

Many of them are worth it, they're cheap ways to promote,

relatively cheaper ways to promote better health.

But it's not going to reduce healthcare spending.

Okay, I can't give you your followup because I have all these other questions.

I will stay after and answer people's questions.

I am gonna kind of, I'm going to go way over here in the corner.

>> About ObamaCare, there's a lot of speculation on the financial impact and

obviously it depends on a lot of things like his decision making and

execution of the program, but if you'd have to take a guess,

do you think it's going to raise our costs or lower our costs, [INAUDIBLE]?

>> Yes, if I were a betting woman, I would say it's going to raise our costs.

That's not a very risky statement for me to make, and

I don't actually like to bet, but when you look at, and this comes

back to a comment I made earlier about the cost to the government or total cost.

When you look at the Affordable Care Acts, when it was first passed when folks said

the Affordable Car Act will reduce heath care spending, or

at least be, not increase it.

They were talking about government spending and

there was a very specific reason for that because in order,

the way the act was passed, it had to be budget neutral, right.

So for every subsidy that they offered someone,

they had to figure out a way to reduce government healthcare spending.

And when the act, and this is over a ten year time period, right,

that the CBO, the Congressional Budget Office actually scores these things,

right, so when the act was passed, there were increases in government spending and

they were offset by reductions in spending.

Those are all estimates, of course.

And folks argued about whether those projections were correct, but

the CBO said, here's our best guess and we think it will be revenue neutral.

At the same time the centers for Medicaid and Medicare service,

the branch of the government that does the national health expenditures and forecasts

healthcare spending, clearly predicted that it would increase healthcare costs.

And the reason for that Is, as I said earlier,

we're bringing a bunch of people into health insurance.

We have 15% of our population at a given time doesn't have any health insurance.

We're the only high income country that leaves

a significant portion of the population out of health insurance schemes.

When you bring people into health insurance, they use more care, and

that costs money, right?

So that idea that healthcare reform was going to reduce healthcare spending,

was really focused on how much the government would pay

overall by bringing more people into health insurance.

It will likely increase healthcare spending.

There is a wildcard here.

The wild card is, remember I talked about all that experimentation that's

happening in the Medicare program.

If that expands, someone hits the jackpot in that experimentation, and

finds something that really works, maybe that will spread.

And the good thing that I think the Affordable Care Act did,

was create some mechanisms for that type of experimentation.

But that's, I think, more uncertain.

Okay, red blazer in the front.

>> In terms of high value versus lower cost,

people looked at the difference that the real need is for

innovation, not cost cutting, and that innovation can only come

trom suppliers and can't come from the buyer, the payer.

And John Goodman who did the health savings account said, I did it,

because I thought the cost would come down, but what really surprised

me was the innovations that hobbled up from the providers.

Now my question is,

do you think 50 million purchasers gave them $10,000 apiece,

would generate more innovation than taking the money from taxpayers and

then trying to put it out from one source with taxpayer money.

And it's not voluntary, instead of customer dollars, which are voluntary.

>> Yeah, so I think innovation is absolutely important, right?

And I think that innovation follows the dollars, right?

So innovating we're here in the valley, so innovation, people innovate,

and the innovations that people think of and

actually get to market are those that they think will sell, right?

So, in the health care system now, our incentives are not

geared towards promoting what I would call high value, low cost innovation, right?

So this fit test is actually a really good example.

So these You know, invaders came up with the fit test, and it's so

much less expensive and equally effective.

But they're having a hard time selling the thing, right,

because lots of people want their colonoscopies.

I would say, because they're really not, I'm probably the only person in

the United States of America who has said that phrase,

lots of people want colonoscopies.

[LAUGH] So if the health care system were redesigned in

some of the ways I think you're talking about,

if people had more incentives to choose these lower

cost plans which are providing fit types of tests,

I think it would fundamentally change the incentives for innovation.

It would be harder, this is actually another really

timely good example in the context of cancer drugs.

Spending on cancer drugs is, or spending on cancer treatment, in general,

is increasing very rapidly, and a lot of that is due to new biologics, new,

different types of cancer drugs which are very,

very expensive and kind of effective, right?

So maybe they increase life by three months on average for

the folks who are taking the drugs.

That is a very difficult decision, right?

Should we be spending tens of thousands of dollars per month for

these very high cost drugs, that have some, but

a limited effect on expected mortality in the overall population, all right?

So if the healthcare system clearly said, no, we're not gonna buy that stuff,

then I think pharmaceutical companies would stop bringing them to market, right?

If the health care assistant says, yes, we are gonna pay for that,

and then we're gonna see more of that type of innovation, right?

So I think the incentives really matter.

Black coat.

>> It seems to me that HSA, CDHP system helps to unite patient incentive and

the provider cost effectiveness.

What does ObamaCare say about the HSA?

>> So the question is about HSAs, which are health saving accounts,

which are paired with high deductible health plans.

Are they effective, and how will

the Affordable Care Act influence their use.

I think that HSAs are, they're going at this, right?

So the idea behind the HSA is if you buy a,

it's like a reward for putting yourself into a high deductible health plan.

So a high deductible health plan is a plan that has a high deductible.

You have to spend a lot of money out of your own pocket,

before your health insurance kicks in.

And the reward for enrolling in one of those plans is, you can set up a,

basically, a tax sheltered savings account.

They're really good deals.

If you guys look into those, those HSAs are a very good place to save your money.

So that's maybe the most important thing you've learned from my talk right now.

>> [LAUGH] >> But

so if you, in terms of their tax treatment.

Okay, so there's a carrot and

there's a stick, the stick is being in the high deductible health plan, and

the carrot is that you get to save your money in this incredibly tax favored way.

I generally think that that is a mechanism.

That's a mechanism that the way that we can promote people

to think about using higher value care.

And the overall evidence on the impact of high deductible health plans and

patient cost sharing, more generally,

is that people do indeed use less care when they are enrolled in those plans.

Of course the thing that we worry about is people are not gonna make the right

decisions, right?

So instead of choosing between colonoscopy and FIT, they're gonna do neither, right?

So that's essentially what we are worried about.

So that's the kind of the con, that's the thing that people worry about.

You know, one of the answers is, can we give folks in those kinds of plans

the right kind of decision support either through their physicians or

through new types of information tools in order to

help them make the right decisions in that type of environment?

What will the Affordable Care Act do to that?

I think it's still a little bit unclear.

I think there will be plans, and the issue here is that

under the Affordable Care Act, there's a minimum generosity level for

plans that plans have to meet, in order to be considered qualified coverage.

So you don't have to pay the individual mandate penalty.

And the question is, can you design a high deductible plan that qualifies you for

getting that nice health savings account, and still meets those qualifications

for the minimum benefit generosity?

And I think there have been some plans that have actually met that criteria.

So I think they will still stay around, and

it depends on people and how the Affordable Care Act shifts demand for

different types of coverage, whether they'll be popular.

Không có nhận xét nào:

Đăng nhận xét